Product Code Database
Example Keywords: glove -data $2
barcode-scavenger
   » » Wiki: Profit Maximization
Tag Wiki 'Profit Maximization'.
Tag

[[File:Profit Maximisation.jpg|thumb|right|An example diagram of Profit Maximization: In the supply and demand graph, the output of Q^* is the intersection point of \text{MR} (Marginal Revenue) and \text{MC} (Marginal Cost), where \text{MR}=\text{MC}. The firm which produces at this output level is said to maximize profits. If the output produced is less than the equilibrium quantity (Q^*), as shown in the red part, then \text{MR} is greater than \text{MC} (\text{MR}>\text{MC}), and the profit is not maximized. The firm has in its interest to raise its output level to maximize profits, because the revenue gained will be more than the cost to pay. However, if the output level is greater than Q^* (\text{MR}<\text{MC}), as shown in the blue part, the firm's overall profit will decrease because the additional unit produced will increase the overall cost. Here too the profit is not maximized and the firm has to lower its output level to maximize profits.]] In , profit maximization is the or process by which a firm may determine the , input and output levels that will lead to the highest possible total profit (or just profit in short). In neoclassical economics, which is currently the mainstream approach to , the is assumed to be a "" (whether operating in a perfectly competitive market or otherwise) which wants to maximize its total profit, which is the difference between its total revenue and its total cost.

Measuring the total cost and total revenue is often impractical, as the firms do not have the necessary reliable information to determine costs at all levels of production. Instead, they take more practical approach by examining how small changes in production influence revenues and costs. When a firm produces an extra unit of product, the additional revenue gained from selling it is called the marginal revenue (\text{MR}), and the additional cost to produce that unit is called the marginal cost (\text{MC}). When the level of output is such that the marginal revenue is equal to the marginal cost (\text{MR}=\text{MC}), then the firm's total profit is said to be maximized. If the marginal revenue is greater than the marginal cost (\text{MR}>\text{MC}), then its total profit is not maximized, because the firm can produce additional units to earn additional profit. In other words, in this case, it is in the "rational" interest of the firm to increase its output level until its total profit is maximized. On the other hand, if the marginal revenue is less than the marginal cost (\text{MR}<\text{MC}), then too its total profit is not maximized, because producing one unit less will reduce total cost more than total revenue gained, thus giving the firm more total profit. In this case, a "rational" firm has an incentive to reduce its output level until its total profit is maximized.

There are several perspectives one can take on profit maximization. First, since profit equals minus , one can plot graphically each of the variables revenue and cost as functions of the level of output and find the output level that maximizes the difference (or this can be done with a table of values instead of a graph). Second, if specific functional forms are known for revenue and cost in terms of output, one can use to maximize profit with respect to the output level. Third, since the first order condition for the optimization equates and , if marginal revenue (\text{MR}) and marginal cost (\text{MC}) functions in terms of output are directly available one can equate these, using either equations or a graph. Fourth, rather than a function giving the cost of producing each potential output level, the firm may have input cost functions giving the cost of acquiring any amount of each input, along with a production function showing how much output results from using any combination of input quantities. In this case one can use calculus to maximize profit with respect to input usage levels, subject to the input cost functions and the production function. The first order condition for each input equates the marginal revenue product of the input (the increment to revenue from selling the product caused by an increment to the amount of the input used) to the marginal cost of the input.

For a firm in a perfectly competitive market for its output, the revenue function will simply equal the market price times the quantity produced and sold, whereas for a , which chooses its level of output simultaneously with its selling price. In the case of monopoly, the company will produce more products because it can still make normal profits. To get the most profit, you need to set higher prices and lower quantities than the competitive market. However, the revenue function takes into account the fact that higher levels of output require a lower price in order to be sold. An analogous feature holds for the input markets: in a perfectly competitive input market the firm's cost of the input is simply the amount purchased for use in production times the market-determined unit input cost, whereas a ’s input price per unit is higher for higher amounts of the input purchased.

The principal difference between short run and long run profit maximization is that in the long run the quantities of all inputs, including , are choice variables, while in the short run the amount of capital is predetermined by past investment decisions. In either case, there are inputs of and .


Basic definitions
Any costs incurred by a may be classified into two groups: and . Fixed costs, which occur only in the short run, are incurred by the business at any level of output, including zero output. These may include equipment maintenance, rent, wages of employees whose numbers cannot be increased or decreased in the short run, and general upkeep. Variable costs change with the level of output, increasing as more product is generated. Materials consumed during production often have the largest impact on this category, which also includes the wages of employees who can be hired and laid off in the short run span of time under consideration. Fixed cost and variable cost, combined, equal .

is the amount of money that a company receives from its normal business activities, usually from the sale of goods and services (as opposed to monies from security sales such as equity shares or debt issuances).

The five ways formula is to increase leads, conversation rates, average dollar sales, the average number of sales, and average product profit. Profits can be increased by up to 1,000 percent, this is important for sole traders and small businesses let alone big businesses but none the less all profit maximization is a matter of each business stage and greater returns for profit sharing thus higher wages and motivation.entrepreneur.com

and , depending on whether the approach is taken or not, are defined as either the change in cost or revenue as each additional unit is produced or the of cost or revenue with respect to the quantity of output. For instance, taking the first definition, if it costs a firm $400 to produce 5 units and $480 to produce 6, the marginal cost of the sixth unit is 80 dollars. Conversely, the marginal income from the production of 6 units is the income from the production of 6 units minus the income from the production of 5 units (the latter item minus the preceding item).


Total revenue – total cost perspective
To obtain the profit maximizing output quantity, we start by recognizing that profit is equal to (\text{TR}) minus (\text{TC}). Given a table of costs and revenues at each quantity, we can either compute equations or plot the data directly on a graph. The profit-maximizing output is the one at which this difference reaches its maximum.

In the accompanying diagram, the linear total revenue curve represents the case in which the firm is a perfect competitor in the goods market, and thus cannot set its own selling price. The profit-maximizing output level is represented as the one at which total revenue is the height of \text{C} and total cost is the height of \text{B}; the maximal profit is measured as the length of the segment \overline{\text{CB}}. This output level is also the one at which the total profit curve is at its maximum.

If, contrary to what is assumed in the graph, the firm is not a perfect competitor in the output market, the price to sell the product at can be read off the at the firm's optimal quantity of output. This optimal quantity of output is the quantity at which equals .


Marginal revenue – marginal cost perspective
An equivalent perspective relies on the relationship that, for each unit sold, (\text{M}\pi) equals marginal revenue (\text{MR}) minus marginal cost (\text{MC}). Then, if marginal revenue is greater than marginal cost at some level of output, marginal profit is positive and thus a greater quantity should be produced, and if marginal revenue is less than marginal cost, marginal profit is negative and a lesser quantity should be produced. At the output level at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost, marginal profit is zero and this quantity is the one that maximizes profit. Since total profit increases when marginal profit is positive and total profit decreases when marginal profit is negative, it must reach a maximum where marginal profit is zero—where marginal cost equals marginal revenue—and where lower or higher output levels give lower profit levels.Lipsey (1975). pp. 245–47. In calculus terms, the requirement that the optimal output have higher profit than adjacent output levels is that:

\frac{\operatorname d^2 R}{\Delta Q} \\
 = & \frac{P\Delta Q+Q \Delta P}{\Delta Q} \\
  = & P+\frac{Q \Delta P}{\Delta Q} \\
     
\end{align}

, where P and Q refer to the midpoints between the old and new values of price and quantity respectively. The marginal revenue from an incremental unit of output has two parts: first, the revenue the firm gains from selling the additional units or, giving the term P\Delta Q. The additional units are called the marginal units.Besanko, D. and Beautigam, R, (2001) p. 408. Producing one extra unit and selling it at price P brings in revenue of P. Moreover, one must consider "the revenue the firm loses on the units it could have sold at the higher price"—that is, if the price of all units had not been pulled down by the effort to sell more units. These units that have lost revenue are called the infra-marginal units. That is, selling the extra unit results in a small drop in price which reduces the revenue for all units sold by the amount Q \cdot \left( \frac{\Delta P}{\Delta Q}\right). Thus, \text{MR} = P + Q \cdot \frac{\Delta P}{\Delta Q} = P + P \cdot \frac{Q}{P} \cdot \frac{\Delta P}{\Delta Q} = P + \frac{P}{\text{PED}}, where \text{PED} is the price elasticity of demand characterizing the demand curve of the firms' customers, which is negative. Then setting \text{MC} = \text{MR} gives \text{MC} = P + \frac{P}{\text{PED}} so \frac{P - \text{MC}}{P} = \frac{-1}{\text{PED}} and P = \frac{MC}{1 + \left(\frac{1}{\text{PED}}\right)}. Thus, the optimal markup rule is:

\frac{\left( P - \text{MC} \right)}{P} = \frac{1}{\left( -\text{PED}\right)}

or equivalently

P = \frac{\text{PED}}{1 + \text{PED}} \cdot \text{MC}.Samuelson, W and Marks, S (2003). p. 103–05.Pindyck, R and Rubinfeld, D (2001) p. 341.

In other words, the rule is that the size of the markup of price over the marginal cost is inversely related to the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for the good.

The optimal markup rule also implies that a non-competitive firm will produce on the elastic region of its market demand curve. Marginal cost is positive. The term \frac{PED}{1+\text{PED}} would be positive so P>0 only if \text{PED} is between -1 and -\infty (that is, if demand is elastic at that level of output).Besanko and Braeutigam (2005) p. 419. The intuition behind this result is that, if demand is inelastic at some value Q_1 then a decrease in Q would increase P more than proportionately, thereby increasing revenue P \cdot Q; since lower Q would also lead to lower total cost, profit would go up due to the combination of increased revenue and decreased cost. Thus, Q_1 does not give the highest possible profit.


Marginal product of labor, marginal revenue product of labor, and profit maximization
The general rule is that the firm maximizes profit by producing that quantity of output where marginal revenue equals . The profit maximization issue can also be approached from the input side. That is, what is the profit maximizing usage of the variable input? Samuelson, W and Marks, S (2003). p. 230. To maximize profit the firm should increase usage of the input "up to the point where the input's marginal revenue product equals its marginal costs".Samuelson, W and Marks, S (2003). p. 23. Mathematically, the profit-maximizing rule is \text{MRP}_L = \text{MC}_L, where the subscript _L refers to the commonly assumed variable input, labor.

The marginal revenue product is the change in total revenue per unit change in the variable input, that is, \text{MRP}_L = \frac{\Delta \text{TR}}{\Delta L}.

\text{MRP}_L is the product of marginal revenue and the marginal product of labor or \text{MRP}_L = \text{MR} \cdot \text{MP}_L.


Criticism
The maximization of can in some cases reduce . Some forms of producer profit maximization are considered anti-competitive practices and are regulated by . Maximization of short-term producer profit can reduce long-term producer profit, which can be exploited by predatory pricing such as dumping.


Government Regulation
Market quotas reflect the power of a firm in the market, a firm dominating a market is very common, and too much power often becomes the motive for non-Hong behavior. Predatory pricing, tying, and other behaviors are reflecting the crisis of excessive power of monopolists in the market. In an attempt to prevent businesses from abusing their power to maximize their own profits, often intervene to stop them in their tracks. A major example of this is through which effectively outlaws most industry . Through this regulation, consumers enjoy a better relationship with the companies that serve them, even though the company itself may suffer, financially speaking.


See also


Notes


External links

Page 1 of 1
1
Page 1 of 1
1

Account

Social:
Pages:  ..   .. 
Items:  .. 

Navigation

General: Atom Feed Atom Feed  .. 
Help:  ..   .. 
Category:  ..   .. 
Media:  ..   .. 
Posts:  ..   ..   .. 

Statistics

Page:  .. 
Summary:  .. 
1 Tags
10/10 Page Rank
5 Page Refs
1s Time